Unit 3: Production, Cost, and the Perfect Competition Model
Students will explore the factors that drive the behavior of companies and learn about the perfect competition model.
The Production Function
Short-Run vs. Long-Run Production
- The production function describes the relationship between inputs (factors of production like labor and capital) and the output of goods and services. In the short run, at least one input (usually capital, like machines or buildings) is fixed, while other inputs like labor can vary. This means firms can adjust labor hours or raw materials, but they cannot quickly build a new factory. In the long run, all inputs are variable, and firms can adjust their plant size, enter or exit industries, and adopt new technologies.
- This distinction is critical because it changes how firms respond to demand and cost pressures. Short-run adjustments are constrained and explain why costs like fixed rent or capital persist regardless of output. Long-run flexibility, however, allows firms to reorganize production completely, leading to economies or diseconomies of scale. On exams, always state explicitly whether a problem is short-run or long-run, since the analysis differs.
Total Product, Marginal Product, and Average Product
- Total product (TP) is the total output produced by a given quantity of inputs. Marginal product (MP) is the additional output gained from using one more unit of input, defined as \[ MP = \frac{\Delta TP}{\Delta L} \] where \(L\) is labor. Average product (AP) is output per unit of input, defined as \[ AP = \frac{TP}{L}. \] These measures show how productivity changes as inputs increase.
- When MP is above AP, it pulls AP upward; when MP is below AP, it pulls AP downward. This is like a student’s test score raising or lowering their average grade. The point where MP intersects AP at AP’s maximum is a standard relationship to remember. It highlights how marginal values drive averages, a concept that appears repeatedly across economics.
- Graphically, the TP curve slopes upward at first but eventually flattens due to diminishing returns. The MP curve typically rises, reaches a peak, and then declines. The AP curve also rises and falls but is always “chased” by the MP curve. Understanding these shapes prepares you for analyzing cost curves in the next section.
The Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns
- The law of diminishing marginal returns states that as more variable input (like labor) is added to a fixed input (like capital), the additional output from each new unit of labor eventually decreases. This happens because the fixed input becomes a bottleneck—too many workers crowd around the same machine, reducing efficiency. Diminishing returns are not about “bad workers,” but about the limits of fixed resources.
- This law only applies in the short run because at least one input is fixed. In the long run, firms can expand all inputs, and diminishing returns are replaced by the analysis of economies of scale. Recognizing this distinction is key to avoiding confusion between short-run productivity and long-run cost structures. On AP exams, explicitly link diminishing returns to the presence of fixed inputs.
- Real-world examples include farms where adding more workers eventually yields smaller increases in harvest per worker, or restaurants where too many cooks in a small kitchen slow production. This principle explains why marginal cost curves eventually rise, since each extra unit of output requires more input than before. It is a cornerstone concept that connects production and cost analysis.
Phases of the Production Function
- Production can be divided into three stages: Stage I (increasing returns), Stage II (diminishing returns), and Stage III (negative returns). In Stage I, each additional worker adds more output than the previous one because specialization and teamwork increase productivity. In Stage II, output still rises but at a decreasing rate because fixed resources limit efficiency. Stage III occurs when too many inputs reduce total output, as workers actively get in each other’s way.
- Firms operate in Stage II because that is where marginal product is positive but diminishing. Stage I is underutilization, while Stage III is outright waste. This framework helps explain why firms hire until MP starts falling but not below zero. On exams, be ready to identify stages on a TP, MP, or AP graph and justify why firms avoid Stages I and III.
Short-Run Production Costs
Fixed Costs, Variable Costs, and Total Costs
- In the short run, firms face both fixed costs (FC) and variable costs (VC). Fixed costs do not change with output — examples include rent, insurance, or salaried management. Variable costs change with output — examples include wages for hourly workers, raw materials, and utilities tied to production. Total cost (TC) is the sum: \[ TC = FC + VC. \] This breakdown is critical because it shows which costs a firm can avoid in the short run (variable) versus those it must pay regardless of output (fixed).
- Fixed costs remain constant as output rises, but average fixed cost (AFC = FC/Q) falls as output expands, because the fixed cost is spread across more units. This “spreading effect” explains why AFC always declines. Variable costs rise as output rises because more inputs are needed, and this drives changes in marginal and average cost curves. Always specify whether you’re describing total or per-unit costs on an exam.
Average and Marginal Costs
- Average total cost (ATC) is the total cost per unit: \[ ATC = \frac{TC}{Q} = \frac{FC}{Q} + \frac{VC}{Q}. \] Average variable cost (AVC) is VC/Q, and average fixed cost (AFC) is FC/Q. Marginal cost (MC) is the additional cost of producing one more unit: \[ MC = \frac{\Delta TC}{\Delta Q}. \] MC reflects the cost of the marginal product of labor and is closely tied to the law of diminishing returns.
- The relationship between MC and the product curves is key: when marginal product rises, marginal cost falls; when marginal product falls, marginal cost rises. This inverse link is why the MC curve is U-shaped. It highlights how input productivity determines per-unit costs. Students should always connect diminishing marginal returns to rising marginal costs.
- Graphically, the MC curve always intersects both AVC and ATC at their minimum points. This is because when MC is below an average, it pulls the average down; when it is above, it pushes the average up. This relationship mirrors the earlier rule with MP and AP. Understanding these intersections helps you quickly sketch correct cost curves.
Shapes and Relationships of Cost Curves
- Cost curves have predictable shapes: AFC slopes downward, AVC and ATC are U-shaped, and MC is also U-shaped. The U-shape arises because of diminishing marginal returns in the short run. Initially, increasing efficiency lowers cost, but as diminishing returns set in, costs rise again. Recognizing these shapes makes drawing graphs much faster in timed settings.
- The vertical distance between ATC and AVC shrinks as output increases, because AFC spreads thinner with more production. At very high quantities, ATC and AVC nearly converge. This pattern allows you to check your diagrams for consistency. On AP FRQs, always label all four curves (AFC, AVC, ATC, MC) if asked.
- Marginal cost is the “driver” of average costs. If MC is less than ATC, then ATC falls; if MC is greater than ATC, then ATC rises. The same rule applies for AVC. This dynamic explains the shape of the cost curves and connects directly to how firms make production decisions. It reinforces the broader marginal analysis principle from Unit 1.
Short-Run Shutdown Condition
- In the short run, a firm should continue producing as long as price (P) covers average variable cost (AVC), even if it is losing money overall. This is because the firm can at least pay part of its fixed costs if it covers variable costs. If P falls below AVC, the firm should shut down immediately because it cannot cover even variable costs, and continuing would increase losses.
- The shutdown condition is expressed as: \[ P \geq AVC \quad \text{→ produce in short run} \] \[ P < AVC \quad \text{→ shut down in short run.} \] This rule is tested often in multiple choice and free-response questions. Always emphasize that shutdown is different from permanent exit, which is a long-run decision.
- This connects directly to efficiency: staying open when P ≥ AVC maximizes resource use in the short run, even if not profitable. It also prepares you for the perfect competition model, where firms adjust to losses and exit in the long run. On exam essays, clearly state “covering variable costs but not fixed costs” to earn full credit.
Long-Run Production Costs
Economies of Scale
- Economies of scale occur when long-run average total cost (LRATC) falls as output increases. This happens because firms spread fixed costs over more units, use inputs more efficiently, and gain bargaining power with suppliers. For example, a car manufacturer can lower per-unit costs by buying materials in bulk and using assembly lines more effectively. This explains why large firms often dominate industries with high fixed costs, like airlines or technology.
- Sources of economies of scale include specialization of labor, better use of capital, bulk purchasing of inputs, and spreading research and development costs across larger output. The result is a downward-sloping LRATC curve over a certain range. This shows how firm growth in the long run can reduce average costs and make large-scale production more competitive.
- Economies of scale link directly to efficiency. By lowering costs per unit, firms can produce at prices closer to marginal cost, benefiting consumers with lower prices. On AP exams, always connect falling LRATC to increasing efficiency and explain why firms expand production to capture these benefits.
Diseconomies of Scale
- Diseconomies of scale occur when LRATC rises as output increases. This typically happens when firms grow too large and face coordination, communication, or management problems. For example, a multinational corporation may struggle with bureaucracy, making decision-making slow and inefficient. At this stage, producing more actually increases per-unit costs.
- Causes of diseconomies of scale include worker alienation, duplication of tasks, poor communication between departments, and excessive layers of management. These factors reduce productivity, even if the firm continues expanding. The LRATC curve begins sloping upward once these inefficiencies outweigh economies of scale.
- Diseconomies highlight the importance of firm size limits. While expansion may be profitable at first, beyond a point, growth harms efficiency. On exams, be prepared to explain that not all growth is beneficial and that bigger is not always better in cost terms.
Constant Returns to Scale
- Constant returns to scale occur when LRATC remains unchanged as output increases. This means doubling all inputs exactly doubles output, so per-unit costs stay constant. In this range, firms neither gain nor lose efficiency as they expand production. The LRATC curve is flat during this stage.
- Constant returns to scale are important because they represent the output level where a firm is operating at its most stable efficiency. Firms in this range have no incentive to expand or contract significantly based on cost considerations alone. This concept demonstrates that not all industries push toward monopolies — some can sustain many mid-sized firms efficiently.
Long-Run Average Total Cost (LRATC) Curve
- The LRATC curve is made up of many short-run ATC curves, each representing a different plant size or level of fixed input. In the long run, firms can choose whichever plant size minimizes average costs at a given level of output. The LRATC is thus the “envelope curve” of all possible short-run ATC curves. This shows how flexibility in the long run changes cost structure.
- The LRATC curve is typically U-shaped: falling at first due to economies of scale, flattening during constant returns, and rising at high output due to diseconomies of scale. This shape explains why firms expand only to a certain point and then stop. The curve highlights the optimal scale of production in the long run.
Minimum Efficient Scale (MES)
- The minimum efficient scale is the smallest quantity of output at which LRATC is minimized. At MES, firms have fully exploited economies of scale and are producing at the lowest possible per-unit cost. Beyond MES, additional output does not reduce costs further. This concept helps explain industry structure and competition.
- If MES is small relative to total market demand, many firms can operate efficiently, leading to competitive industries. If MES is large relative to demand, only a few firms can reach efficient scale, leading to oligopoly or even natural monopoly. For example, electricity providers face high fixed costs, so MES is very large, while small bakeries face a small MES and can compete widely. On AP exams, always connect MES to market structure.
Types of Profit
Accounting Profit
- Accounting profit is the difference between total revenue (TR) and explicit costs, which are the actual out-of-pocket payments a firm makes. Explicit costs include expenses like wages, rent, raw materials, and utilities. The formula is \[ \text{Accounting Profit} = TR - \text{Explicit Costs}. \] This is the profit figure reported on financial statements and used for tax purposes. It measures profitability in the traditional business sense.
- Because it only subtracts explicit costs, accounting profit tends to be larger than economic profit. For example, if a bakery earns \$100,000 in revenue and spends \$60,000 on wages and ingredients, accounting profit is \$40,000. However, this ignores the opportunity costs of the owner’s time and capital. On AP exams, always note that accounting profit is a narrower measure of profitability.
Economic Profit
- Economic profit is total revenue minus both explicit and implicit costs. Implicit costs represent the opportunity costs of using resources in their current way rather than in the next best alternative. The formula is \[ \text{Economic Profit} = TR - (\text{Explicit Costs} + \text{Implicit Costs}). \] This broader measure captures whether a firm is truly earning more than it could by deploying resources elsewhere.
- For example, if the bakery’s owner could earn \$30,000 as a manager elsewhere, that foregone salary is an implicit cost. If the bakery’s accounting profit is \$40,000 but implicit costs are \$30,000, economic profit is only \$10,000. If total implicit and explicit costs equal revenue, economic profit is zero. This is called normal profit, explained below.
- Economic profit is central to firm decision-making. Positive economic profit means resources are earning above their opportunity cost, attracting new firms to enter the market in the long run. Negative economic profit signals resources are better used elsewhere, prompting firms to exit. This explains long-run adjustments in competitive markets.
Normal Profit
- Normal profit occurs when total revenue equals total costs (explicit + implicit). In this case, economic profit equals zero. This does not mean the firm is “failing” — it means the firm is covering all explicit expenses and earning just enough to compensate for opportunity costs. The owner is doing as well here as they would in their next best alternative.
- Normal profit is considered a cost of production because it represents the minimum return necessary to keep a firm in business. Firms earning normal profit have no incentive to leave the industry, but they also do not attract new entrants. This condition defines long-run equilibrium in perfectly competitive markets.
- On AP exams, it’s crucial to distinguish between zero economic profit (normal profit) and zero accounting profit (a loss). Many students confuse these terms, but they mean very different things. Always specify which type of profit is being calculated.
Short-Run vs. Long-Run Profits
- In the short run, firms may earn positive economic profit, normal profit, or losses because the number of firms is fixed. Positive profits attract entry in the long run, while losses cause exit. In the long run, entry and exit drive economic profit to zero, leaving firms with only normal profit. This ensures resources flow to their most valued uses.
- Short-run profits can occur when demand is high, when firms have unique advantages, or when supply is temporarily limited. Conversely, recessions may cause short-run losses. Long-run adjustments smooth out these fluctuations. This dynamic adjustment is a defining feature of competitive markets.
Profit Maximization for Firms
The MR = MC Rule
- The fundamental rule of profit maximization is that firms should produce the quantity of output where marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC). This condition ensures that the last unit produced adds exactly as much to revenue as it does to cost. If MR > MC, the firm should expand output; if MR < MC, the firm should reduce output. Producing at MR = MC maximizes economic profit or minimizes loss.
- In perfectly competitive markets, MR is equal to price (P) because each unit is sold at the same market price. This means firms produce until P = MC. This condition highlights how competitive markets allocate resources efficiently, ensuring output continues until marginal benefit (P) equals marginal cost. On AP exams, always emphasize that the MR = MC rule applies to all market structures, though MR differs across them.
Graphical Analysis of Profit and Loss
- Profit or loss can be determined by comparing average total cost (ATC) to price at the profit-maximizing output. If P > ATC at QMR=MC, the firm earns positive economic profit. If P = ATC, the firm earns zero economic profit (normal profit). If P < ATC but P ≥ AVC, the firm operates at a loss but continues in the short run. These outcomes are essential to show with shaded areas on graphs.
- Graphically, profit is represented by a rectangle where height = (P – ATC) and width = Q. A loss is represented by a rectangle where height = (ATC – P) and width = Q. Being able to shade profit and loss areas quickly and correctly is an easy way to score diagram points on the exam. Always mark QMR=MC, P, ATC, and AVC clearly.
Shut-Down Decision in the Short Run
- If price is below AVC, the firm should shut down immediately because it cannot cover variable costs. Continuing to operate would only increase losses since fixed costs must still be paid regardless. In this case, shutting down limits losses to the amount of fixed costs. This is the shut-down rule and applies only in the short run.
- If price is above AVC but below ATC, the firm produces in the short run even though it incurs a loss. It does so because it can at least cover variable costs and part of its fixed costs. Over time, however, if losses persist, the firm will exit the market in the long run. This rule explains why firms may continue operating temporarily despite negative profits.
Connection to Long-Run Equilibrium
- In the long run, firms will enter if existing firms earn positive economic profits, shifting supply right and lowering price until profits return to zero. Conversely, firms exit if losses occur, shifting supply left and raising price until remaining firms break even. This entry-exit mechanism ensures that long-run equilibrium in perfect competition results in normal profit for all firms.
- This adjustment process guarantees both productive efficiency (firms produce at the lowest point on the ATC curve) and allocative efficiency (P = MC). These efficiency results distinguish perfect competition from other market structures. On AP exams, clearly linking MR = MC to both profit maximization and efficiency outcomes is crucial.
The Perfect Competition Model
Characteristics of Perfect Competition
- Perfect competition describes an idealized market structure where many small firms sell identical products. Because the product is standardized, buyers cannot distinguish one firm’s output from another’s. Firms are price takers, meaning they accept the market price set by overall supply and demand. This assumption ensures that no single firm has market power.
- Additional assumptions include free entry and exit in the long run, perfect information for buyers and sellers, and zero transaction costs. These conditions create an environment where firms cannot influence price, and efficiency outcomes naturally arise. On AP exams, always list these characteristics clearly — missing even one condition may cost points on FRQs.
The Firm’s Demand Curve in Perfect Competition
- In a perfectly competitive market, the individual firm faces a perfectly elastic (horizontal) demand curve at the market price. This means the firm can sell as much output as it wants at the market price but nothing at a higher price. The firm’s demand curve is also its marginal revenue (MR) curve and its average revenue (AR) curve. Therefore, in perfect competition, P = MR = AR = Demand.
- This is very different from the downward-sloping market demand curve. While the entire market faces a typical demand curve, the individual firm is too small to affect price and thus faces a flat demand line. On diagrams, always show the firm’s demand as a horizontal line at P, labeling it as D = MR = AR = P. This detail is frequently tested.
Short-Run Equilibrium
- In the short run, firms maximize profit where MR = MC. Depending on market price, they may earn positive economic profit, normal profit, or losses. If price exceeds ATC at QMR=MC, the firm earns profit. If price equals ATC, the firm earns normal profit. If price is between AVC and ATC, the firm operates at a loss but stays open. If price is below AVC, the firm shuts down.
- These outcomes show how competitive firms respond to different market prices in the short run. Firms are constrained by fixed inputs and cannot adjust plant size or fully exit the market immediately. Graphical analysis should always include MC, ATC, AVC, and the horizontal demand line. Correctly shading profit or loss areas demonstrates mastery.
Long-Run Equilibrium
- In the long run, free entry and exit drive all firms to earn zero economic profit (normal profit). If firms earn short-run profit, new firms enter, shifting market supply right and lowering price until profits disappear. If firms face losses, some exit, shifting market supply left and raising price until remaining firms break even. This process ensures that only normal profit persists in the long run.
- Long-run equilibrium occurs where P = MC = minimum ATC. At this point, firms are producing at their most efficient scale. The condition P = MC ensures allocative efficiency (resources allocated where MB = MC), while production at minimum ATC ensures productive efficiency (goods produced at lowest per-unit cost). These efficiency outcomes are unique to perfect competition.
Efficiency in Perfect Competition
- Allocative efficiency occurs when P = MC, meaning resources are allocated to produce the goods most valued by society. In perfect competition, this condition always holds at equilibrium. Every unit with MB ≥ MC is produced, and no units with MC > MB are wasted. This ensures maximum net benefits for society.
- Productive efficiency occurs when firms produce at the lowest possible cost, which is at the minimum point of ATC. In the long run, competitive forces ensure firms reach this point. This means society gets goods at the lowest possible prices. On exams, always state that perfect competition achieves both allocative and productive efficiency in the long run.
- This dual efficiency outcome sets perfect competition apart from all other market structures. Monopoly, oligopoly, and monopolistic competition fail to achieve both. Perfect competition is therefore used as a benchmark for evaluating real-world markets.